The Case Against Globalisation Reparations
There are a lot of column inches currently being devoted to
an increasingly popular idea: That the
benefits of globalisation and free trade haven’t been sufficiently broadly spread and something must be done.
This has been variously conceived in the form “globalisation’s
losers”, “Rust Belt rebellion” and “back row kids” and has been placed at the
centre of the anti-establishment wave sweeping developed economies. Without
wanting to antagonise the no doubt well-meaning authors of such pieces,
however, I’m not at all convinced that at this stage addressing national
inequality using globalisation reparations frame is a good guide for public
policy.
For an example of this argument, see Gavyn Davies recent
column in the FT (emphasis mine):
“Economists have now recognised these dangers, and a new consensus has started to emerge. There has been (almost) no change in the overwhelming belief that free trade and globalisation are good things for society as a whole. But it is now much more widely accepted that the losers from these changes can be more numerous, more long lasting and more politically assertive than previously thought.
The new consensus holds that the gains from globalisation can only be defended and extended if the losers are compensated by the winners. Otherwise, pockets of political resistance to the process of globalisation will begin to overwhelm the gainers, even though the latter remain in the majority.”
I think this consensus, if it is such, is not only unhelpful
but potentially highly economically and socially corrosive. To see why, you
need first to look at what we mean by globalisation losers.
There is little doubt that the most immediate
impact of opening up global trade, in particular the emergence of China as a
global trade power from the 1990s, was disruptive and ultimately helped drive the dismantling of
large sections of the manufacturing base of the developed world. As the
FT’s Matt Klein illustrates, although a great deal of US manufacturing jobs
would likely have been lost to technological advancement the impact of import
competition has also been significant – in the no import competition model Klein
suggests the manufacturing workforce could be some 19% bigger than it is today.
But even acknowledging the significant disruptive influence
of opening up global trade on huge swathes of domestic industries and
communities that relied on them, compensation for globalisation losers remains
a poor framework to guide public policy. Where it is useful is in adjusting
future approaches to positive supply shocks from free trade, ensuring that
re-training programmes are available for affected employees, providing incentives
for corporates to re-locate to affected areas, that targeted investment in
communities to build long-term assets are considered as well as direct
transfers such as unemployment benefits.
Perhaps most importantly, policy needs to insure that income
shocks don’t create a vicious cycle of lower asset prices leading to negative equity/high
indebtedness and effectively trapping people into poverty.
Yet there is a reason why the rust belt has got its name. In
short, these policies weren’t in place early enough to prevent the decline of
former industrial towns and cities. Moreover, there is also a consensus
among economists that, absent significant import tariffs and quotas providing a
substantial self-imposed negative supply shock creating a worse problem than the one you’re trying to solve, there is no way for the US to bring back these
manufacturing jobs.
Indeed, large parts of the so-called rust belt are already a
fair way into the transition out of industrial decline and integrating well
into the modern services economy. The "Rust Belt" states have seen significant net job gains over the past decade, and
while the unemployment rate is (on average) somewhat higher than the national
average the participation rate in most rust belt states is above the national
average in all save Pennsylvania.
That is not to suggest these regions don’t have problems,
only that the practical problems they have – urban/rural disparities, poverty, education
gaps – are common to a number of areas and communities outside of
de-industrialised areas. What proponents of the globalisation reparations
argument seem to suggest is that, rather than address those as issues of
national importance, we should instead privilege industrial towns because they
appear to be angriest about their relative status change.
I am simply not convinced that putting relative
status above actual need in a hierarchy of concerns for public policy is either
sensible or desirable. And, moreover, it privileges a certain type of
disenfranchisement – the decline of the factory worker and their perceived place
in the American mythos – over other disadvantaged communities who have long been
fighting to close a status and income gap that remains one of the biggest
indictments of policy to date.
Indeed, the closing of that gap between the white working
class and traditionally marginalised groups may have made that status anxiety
all the more acute. And the answer surely cannot be to reopen it simply in order
to buy off hostility by the most vocal to globalisation and free trade at the
cost of better policy for everyone. Still less is it an argument for pushing back against openness to trade and migration now that the initial costs have already been experienced - guaranteeing only that they will be less able to partake in the benefits of a faster growing, ever-more-integrated global economy.
Doing so would be to compound rather than learn from the mistakes of the recent past.
Doing so would be to compound rather than learn from the mistakes of the recent past.
Comments
Post a Comment